BLOG POST

Tropical Forests Equal to the Size of India Will Be Lost by 2050, Unless We Act

August 23, 2015

An area of tropical forest the size of India will be deforested in the next 35 years, burning through more than one-sixth of the remaining carbon that can be emitted if global warming is to be kept below 2 degrees Celsius (the “planetary carbon budget”), but many of these emissions could be cheaply avoided by putting a price on carbon.

These are the findings of my new CGD working paper with Jens Engelmann. We projected future emissions from deforestation by combining 18 million satellite-based measurements of forest loss from 2001 to 2012 with tropics-wide information on topography, accessibility, protected areas, crop suitability, and forest carbon stocks. We then estimated how tropical land users would respond to forest conservation policies based on how land users responded to changes in agricultural commodity prices in the recent past.

 

The bad news and the good news

First the bad news. Our projections show a steady rise in deforestation through the 2020s and 2030s and then an acceleration in the 2040s. Unchecked, these trends mean 2.9 million square kilometers (one-seventh the area of the world’s tropical forests circa 2000) will be cleared by 2050. That’s the size of India, or one-third of the entire United States. The carbon dioxide emitted by that destruction will be 169 billion tons—that’s like running 44,000 typical coal plants for a year.[i]

Now the good news. Many of those future emissions from deforestation could be avoided if countries rapidly put a price on carbon. The 169 billion tons of future emissions would be reduced by about one-quarter in response to a $20-per-ton carbon price in tropical forest countries (equivalent to a $9-per-ton average cost to land users, as explained below), or by nearly half in response to a $50-per-ton carbon price ($21-per-ton average cost).

Why reducing tropical deforestation is a bargain

Our numbers suggest that reducing tropical deforestation offers a large and cheap way to fight climate change relative to other sources of emissions. Tropical deforestation produced nearly as many annual emissions as the European Union from 2001 to 2012. But whereas the EU could cut emissions by only about 5 percent at $20-per-ton in 2020,[ii] reducing tropical deforestation could cut emissions by 4.5 times as much at that price. That means reducing emissions by conserving tropical forests costs about one-fifth of what it costs to reduce the same amount of emissions in the EU. Relative to California, another jurisdiction with carbon pricing in place, reducing tropical deforestation offers about 55 times as many low-cost emission reductions (see figure 1) [iii]..

Figure 1: Reducing tropical deforestation is a bargain for fighting climate change

graph of costs of carbon emission reductions in EU, California, and via forest protection

Of course, carbon pricing is just one policy for reducing deforestation. Governments might find other policies cheaper or easier to implement, often by imposing restrictions on land users. Brazil tamed Amazon deforestation using satellite monitoring, law enforcement, new protected areas and indigenous territories, restrictions on rural credit, and moratoriums on unsustainable soy and cattle production. As a result of these restrictive measures, Amazon deforestation fell by nearly 80 percent since 2004 even while Brazil’s soy and cattle production increased. In our paper we considered Brazil’s restrictive policy approach as an alternative to carbon pricing. We project that if all tropical countries put in place anti-deforestation policies as effective as those enacted by Brazil in the Amazon in the last decade, one-third of future tropical forest loss and associated emissions would be avoided. Combining restrictive measures with a $20-per-ton carbon price would cut future emissions in half.

Tropical forests: a win for both climate and development

That tropical forests offer so many low-cost emission reductions shows the potential benefits of international carbon payments, whereby rich countries pay tropical countries for keeping their forests standing. Rich countries would fight climate change more cheaply; forest countries would receive a new, green source of income that could be used to alleviate poverty. Win, win. International carbon payments have been pioneered in Brazil and Guyana at a carbon price of $5/tCO2, as well as in Indonesia and through the multilateral Carbon Fund. Our research suggests such efforts have lots of room to grow.

It is worth noting that the average cost to land users of reducing emissions is considerably lower than the hypothetical carbon market price—a $20/tCO2 carbon price implies a $9/tCO2 average cost, while a $50/tCO2 carbon price implies a $21/tCO2 average cost. In a pure carbon market the difference between the (lower) cost and the (higher) price would go as profit to land users who supply emission reductions. In practice the distribution of profits and costs from reducing emissions depends on whether forest countries’ policies favor carrots or sticks, as well as the volume of carbon payments from rich countries to forest countries.

Let’s put these costs in perspective. Not only are the costs of reducing deforestation low relative to the costs of reducing emissions in other sectors, they’re also low relative to climate damages from deforestation. The United States government’s official estimate of the social cost of carbon is around $40/tCO2 and rising; if climate change negatively affects economic growth then the cost could be several times higher. This is even before considering other domestic costs arising from deforestation—dirtier water, drought, and the like.

Watch a clip from CGD's podcast with Jonah Busch.

Our paper is not the first to estimate the marginal abatement costs of reducing deforestation (see here, here, here, here, and here from 5 to 10 years ago). But ours is the first to use groundbreaking annual satellite data on forest loss from 2001 to 2012 rather than the haphazard numbers that countries self-report to the Food and Agricultural Organization every five years. While previous studies projected that tropical deforestation will gradually decline under business as usual, patterns visible in the satellite data of how deforestation has historically spread non-linearly lead us to project that tropical deforestation will accelerate in coming decades as currently remote forest areas come under increasing pressure. And while our cost estimates are more conservative than previous studies, we still find that reducing tropical deforestation represents a sizable and relatively low-cost option for mitigating climate change.

Land users deforest more when agricultural prices are high, and they deforest less when agricultural prices are low; this empirical relationship underpins our model. This relationship varies from year to year and from place to place (higher responsiveness to prices in Asia and lower responsiveness in Latin America, according to our analysis). Importantly, land users’ responsiveness to prices is malleable through policy—land users in the Amazon were less responsive to agricultural prices after Brazil put its anti-deforestation policies in place. How much deforestation we can expect in the future depends to a large degree on future agricultural prices. These and other nuances of the analysis are discussed in greater detail in the working paper.

Encouragingly, 89 percent of the future low-cost emission reductions are in tropical countries that have already signaled their intention to reduce emissions from deforestation in exchange for performance-based finance (REDD+), see figure 2 below. Sixty-three percent of low-cost emission reductions are in the seven countries that have signed pay-for-performance agreements with Norway or Germany to reduce deforestation (Brazil, Colombia, Ecuador, Guyana, Indonesia, Liberia, Peru). Another 26 percent of low-cost emission reductions are in 40 additional countries that have joined a multilateral program for REDD+ (FCPF, UN-REDD, or FIP).

From commitments to finance

This is a big year for the climate, with a United Nations summit in December in Paris. Many tropical countries have committed to reduce deforestation if finance is made available (through the UN climate agreement as well as commitments such as the New York Declaration on Forests and the Lima Challenge). Now it’s time for rich countries to match these commitments with performance-based finance. Reducing tropical deforestation can cut nearly five times as many emissions as Europe can at the same price—that’s a deal for the climate that’s too big and too cheap to pass up.

Figure 2: Avoided emissions from deforestation and peat degradation (tCO2/ha) in response to a carbon price of $20/tCO2, 2016­–2050

map showing intensity of emission reductions in the tropics


[i] Authors’ calculations based on Greenhouse Gas Equivalencies Calculator, Environmental Protection Agency http://www.epa.gov/cleanenergy/energy-resources/calculator.html

[ii] Authors’ calculations based on Global Climate Assessment Model (GCAM) http://wiki.umd.edu/gcam/.

[iii] Authors’ calculations based on Air Resources Board (2010). Updated economic analysis of California’s Climate Change Scoping Plan. Air Resources Board, California Environmental Protection Agency. Sacramento, California.

 

 

Disclaimer

CGD blog posts reflect the views of the authors, drawing on prior research and experience in their areas of expertise. CGD is a nonpartisan, independent organization and does not take institutional positions.