BLOG POST

Three Ways to Ensure COP-26 Delivers for Poor People

February 11, 2021

Recommended

COP-26—the latest global gathering of parties to the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change—meets in Glasgow this November. Six years after the Paris climate conference, the conference will mark the passage of new “Nationally Determined Contributions:” country commitments to reduce carbon emissions ahead of 2030. But it will also revisit a number of long-time controversies, including financing to help developing countries respond to the risk of climate change, carbon markets, and taxes and tariffs on carbon.

How those debates unfold could have a considerable impact on people in the world’s poorest countries —those least responsible for climate change who are likely to suffer the most from its impacts. Three ways that COP-26 could deliver for those countries are to properly define what counts as “new and additional” climate finance, make sure carbon markets rather than aid pays for the additional costs of mitigation in poorer developing countries, and agree to exempt the poorest countries from carbon tariffs.

1. Define “new and additional” (and meet finance targets)

The idea that rich countries should provide finance to help developing countries mitigate climate change (by reducing emissions) or adapt to climate change (through investments like sea walls) has been around for nearly three decades. And for nearly thirty years, rich and poor countries have agreed the resources should be “new and additional.” But despite the agreement in Copenhagen in 2009 that there would be $100 billion a year in climate financing by 2020, confirmed in the Paris agreements, the definition of new and additional wasn’t agreed, so it is difficult to know by how much rich countries have missed their commitments (and there’s no doubt they missed them). And as the world is meant to agree even more ambitious climate finance going forward, this is a problem that will only get worse. COP-26 should fix it.

If the “new and additional” language is meaningless, it should be dropped. If it is meaningful, we should define what it means. One suggestion: any climate finance reported towards the $100 billion target should be “new and additional” in that it is part of a total climate and non-climate financial resource flow above absolute levels of official or mobilized private finance to developing countries by that country prior to an agreed baseline date—perhaps Copenhagen (2009), the Paris Agreement (2015) or COP-26 itself. In addition, if the finance is for a mitigation project, it should be in accordance with the recipient country’s Nationally Determined Contributions.

2. Make sure ODA isn’t diverted to fix problems created by the rich world

A lot of the finance that donor countries have claimed to be delivering towards the $100 billion target comes from their aid budgets (which remain at less than half of the agreed 0.7 percent of GNI target for donor countries as a whole). In order to make sure that ODA is both new and additional and meets the requirement that ODA has as its main objective—the economic development and welfare of developing countries—COP-26 should agree that any finance scored to the $100 billion target and also scored as ODA must meet the following criteria:

  • Be new and additional ODA, that is to say part of a donor country total ODA flow to developing countries that is above ODA flows prior to the agreed baseline date.

  • Generate a significant economic return within the recipient (ODA eligible) economy. For illustrative purposes, this might be taken as equivalent to above a hurdle rate of return on domestic impact of ten percent or higher, although considerable ODA is spent on projects where economic rates of return are hard to calculate.

  • If a mitigation project, must be in accordance with the recipient country’s Nationally Determined Contributions.

An alternate approach would be simply to exclude from ODA counts from projects that are principally designed to reduce greenhouse gas emissions, although this might exclude some projects that have both very high domestic returns and significant mitigation impact (including forest conservation).

In addition, ODA should not be diverted from high impact projects in low-income countries purely on the basis of greenhouse gas implications. For example, COP participants should agree to avoid (explicit or implicit) bans on aid-financed gas power projects. 76 percent of low-income country energy consumption is already from renewable sources, compared to 18 percent in the EU and 9 percent in the US. An over-reliance on intermittent renewable sources is one of the reasons why low-income countries already have unreliable power—they need greater access to power sources like gas-powered plants that can quickly respond to demand fluctuations.  

If rich countries want poorer countries to put in more zero-carbon capacity and the storage mechanisms that it would require in the place of gas, they should pay for it. The same applies to other investments with a high domestic economic return that can be made less emitting at higher cost. But they should do so through the carbon market mechanism envisioned under Article Six of the Paris Accord rather than relying on ODA. The Glasgow COP should agree on the rules behind a carbon market system so that this can start to happen.

3. Agree to exempt the poorest countries from carbon tariffs

A number of countries that are implementing or planning carbon taxes, or cap and trade mechanisms at home, are also considering tariffs on imported goods that come from countries which don’t have a price on carbon.  It would be an awe-inspiring act of hypocrisy for the US, with carbon emissions of 16 metric tons per capita or even the European Union at 6.5 tons per capita, to put a carbon tax on exports from low-income countries with average carbon emissions of 0.3 tons per capita. COP-26 should agree to exclude low income countries from carbon tariff regimes. Or it could agree to exclude countries that emit below a certain absolute level (perhaps 2 tonnes per head) or relative level (perhaps 50 percent of the country applying the tariff). Once again, if rich countries want to encourage the world’s poorest countries to follow a lower-carbon development path than they did, rich countries should pay for the low carbon technologies that allow low-emission production.

There’s a fear that an approach that exempted some countries would lead to arbitrage—firms moving carbon-intensive production of goods like cement and steel to low income countries. More industry in those countries would be welcome—they are home to the world’s poorest people who need better opportunities. It is sad, then, there is no evidence (really, even looking at high emissions sectors) that differential carbon pricing has shifted industries worldwide—other factors are clearly far more important in choosing firm location, and that will apply in particular to low-income countries that face huge infrastructure deficits and have limited human capital. That said, if some high-emitting industries were encouraged to relocate to low income countries, the method to support the use of comparatively low-emissions technologies in those industries is the carbon market and (non-ODA) climate finance.

The world’s poorest people can least afford the costs of climate change: COP-26 needs to deliver dramatic reductions in emissions. But it needs to do that in a way that doesn’t drive poor people further into poverty. Low-income countries see average incomes one 44th of Europe’s and one 80th of America’s at market exchange rates. Rich countries are already negligent on meeting their commitments to deliver assistance to developing countries, COP-26 shouldn’t compound the negligence by diverting what little funding rich countries do provide to fix problems they created while raising further barriers to the poorest countries’ prospects for economic growth.

Thanks to Ian Mitchell, Masood Ahmed, and Andrew Rogerson for very helpful ideas and suggestions.

Disclaimer

CGD blog posts reflect the views of the authors, drawing on prior research and experience in their areas of expertise. CGD is a nonpartisan, independent organization and does not take institutional positions.